Alexander C. Cartwright
There are
currently plenty of ‘crises’ competing for government attention: we are facing
the sequestration crisis, the ongoing debt/spending crisis, along with worries
about Iran, North Korea, North Africa, and a domestic policy debate on gun
control. Government is failing the
citizens on so many fronts that the Left had to celebrate the most recent
unemployment rate and job creation numbers- even though this is the first time
since taking office that unemployment has gone down on President Obama’s watch
and the number of people who gave up looking for work was higher than the
number of new jobs created.
There is
little to celebrate about the results of government action, and sadly, all the
more reason to be concerned about the future. A short lesson in public choice
economics can help us understand that strategies like calling for more or
better leadership are nearly meaningless- what we need to do is look at the
incentives that government officials face and consider the rules and
institutions that give license to the behavior we see.
Our
President is probably so unwilling to cut spending and seems to unconcerned
about the large level of debt we have, not only because he believes that
government spending is an economically feasible way to stimulate an economy,
but also because the federal reserve system’s own policies (setting interest
rates low) make taking on debt very cheap.
Of course,
the President might have an incentive to consider policies addressing
unsustainable spending level if there was a foreseeable end to the FED’s low
interest rate policy. However, after quantitative easing (where the FED buys
securities on the open market- effectively injecting money, created digitally,
into the economy) rounds one, two and three, the FED announced that this once
considered extraordinary measure would become regular policy.
The FED
announced that they would engage in quantitative easing every month until they
become satisfied with the economy’s recovery. Monthly, quantitative easing has
been taking place at the tune of $85 billion per month ever since September
2012. That puts us at about QE10 this month. Considering that new debt is
‘cheap’ and there is no clear end to the FED’s quantitative easing policy, the
left doesn’t face much of an incentive to seriously consider a cut in spending.
Only a little over 6% of the federal budget goes to paying interest on our debt
and, despite taking on more debt, that number has declined in recent years due
to low interest rates.
Quantitative
Easing was a bad policy when it started, and it continues to be a bad policy,
yet no one seems to be talking about the fact that we are on round ten. Instead
of debating which policies should be cut first, when, and by how much, lets
first make politicians are facing an incentive to cut them. One of the most
obvious things we can do is ask why charging Washington bureaucrats, armed with
lots of statistics, with the task of determining the money supply is a
legitimate function of government, and ask why we should expect them to be able
to determine the interest any better than they could determine the price of
milk.
Critics of
this position will most certainly point to the current all time highs in the
financial markets, as evidence of quantitative easing’s success. However, any
gains realized by quantitative easing will not be permanent. As cheap money
enters the economy, investors see profit opportunities- even though they know
these price levels aren’t sustainable long term there is still an opportunity
to make money. It’s hard to sit on the sidelines and watch everyone else profit
in the short term, even if you are certain that the bubble will burst. The
result is a prisoners-dilemma-like situation and the same risky investment
behavior that encouraged the 2008 crash. Simply put, quantitative easing cannot
last forever, and the costs that come with it- via financial markets and by
incentivizing government to take on debt- will be steeper the longer it
continues.
Improving
government performance requires improving the rules and institutions that make
up government and changing the incentives that government actors face. Even
though central banking and macroeconomics are complicated, our Central Bank
gives license to much of the government behavior that makes our society less
prosperous, and incentivizes much of the government behavior that is
undesirable. The FED’s complexity should not insulate it from criticism. Price
fixing, central planning, and manipulating the money supply, have never led to
a just and prosperous society and the Federal Reserve is no exception.
No comments:
Post a Comment